Term
|
Definition
The very complicated economics of consumers and producers. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The production of food and non-food crops. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The person or firm purchasing products or services from the producer. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The firm providing products or services to the consumer. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A logo used by farmers to remind urban-dwellers that they rely on the rural community for sustainance. It reminds them that a real person grew their food. Such assertations may be met by the reply "Cities Buy Food" which is also true. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The method by which consumers communicate with producers their demands. They should be met with appropriate supply, but often the signals are clogged by many layers of marketing. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When supply is equal to demand the market does not work. People need to have choices. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Decisions that must be made by both consumers and producers. Producers must decide about inputs, production, sales, investments. Consumers must decide about consumption, and saving.
We must make these decisions because we cannot have everything we want. There are limited resources, but unlimited wants. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A resource that is not infinite. This is what drives economic choices. Limited resources for consumers are money and time. Limited resources for consumers are money, time, materials, labour, land, and technology. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A physical asset. May be natural, biological, human, or manufactured. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The cost of a foregone use of a resource. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The man who wrote the "Bible" of economics. Came up with the theory of specialization. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The concept that a firm can achieve greater outputs if each section of production is covered by an expert peron in that stage of production. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A social science that deals with production, consumers, and their choices with limited resources. A very broad discipline. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A mode of thinking in economics where you look at what is, what was, and what would happen if something changed. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A mode of thinking in economics where you look at what you think should be. This implies you are expressing your opinions and personal values. |
|
|
Term
Supply and demand diagram |
|
Definition
A graph combining the supply curve and the demand curve of a good or service. Where the two intersect is the market equilibrium. Using this diagram can help to solve many economic problems. It is a useful tool, however it doesn't tell us about the increase or decrease in welfare of buyers and sellers. Only works in a model where there is perfect competition. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The government. The government may apply policies to certain activities. Example: butterfat quota in dairy production. Underly the market, regulations, laws, and legislation. Supply currency, grades, standards. Tries to lower the transaction costs as much as possible.
They may be capitalist, socialist, or mixed. This depends on many things such as history. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An institution style where there is a free market. People may own things and do whatever they want as long as they don't interfere with other people's right to own things and do what they want.
No countries are purely capitalist. All have some involvement by the government such as currency.
17th centuray pirate ships were purely capitalist. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An institution style where the state owns everything. The government decides how all human and non-human resources are going to be used. This perpetuates a high degree of power in the decision-makers. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An institution style that is a mix between capitalism and socialism. Most countries are in this category. The government has institutions that govern the prices in some markets with a long price discovery process. Education, military protection, health care, and product standards and grades are provided by the government. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Looks at how a small change in some economic dimension will effect the rest of the system. Economist are generally concerned with what happens at the margin. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The economic choices of producers. Occurs everywhere in the world. What is being produced, how, and for what changes, but production economics stays the same. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The input of physical things used for production i.e. vehicles, land, machinery, chemicals, ingredients, seeds, buildings. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A production system in which at least on of the inputs is fixed.
Short-run equilibrium is where marginal cost = marginal revenue. There will be profit or loss. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A production system in which there are no fixed inputs.
Equilibrium is where marginal cost = marginal revenue. There is no profit or loss. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Something a firm uses to make outputs. Could be ingredients, labour, capital, genetic stock, information, et cetera. Inputs could be factors of production; outputs from another firm. There can be many inputs for one output.
Inputs are either fixed or variable. Main categories of inputs are: land, labour, capital, and management. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Something a firm produces using inputs. Could be crops, manufactured goods, food, clothing, anything. One firm may produce multiple outputs, such as usable by-products.
Outputs are either conspumption goods or factors of production. |
|
|
Term
The Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns |
|
Definition
If you keep adding one input while keeping all other inputs the same, outputs will increase but at a decreasing rate until it is actually going down. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A relationship between inputs and outputs. Indicates a maximum output that can be produced. It is determined through experiments or by examining past records. This can be altered by a change in inputs or by a technology change. It is expressed using a table, a graph, and/or a mathematical equation.
Tables are good for getting exact information.
Graphs are good for visualizing the information.
Math equations are good for if there are more than one input factors.
y = f(x,z). Where y is output, x and z are the inputs, and f is the production function. The equation can be linear or quadratic. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When a new technology or production method is developed, production functions may change, since the previous production practices may no longer be the most efficient.
It can also effect consumption. The microwave changed what people want to buy. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An input that cannot be changed by the producer i.e. once a crop is planted the producer cannot change the number of plants planted. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An input that the producer can change i.e. the amount of fertilizer a farmer choses to use. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Outputs that are sold directly to a consumer and contribute to their utility. Examples: a cup of hot coffee, a car for personal use, a new T-shirt. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Outputs that are then used as inputs by another firm. Example: raw coffee beans, tractors, fabric. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A type of input. Land also comes with other renewable resources such as minerals, forests, soil biota, and groundwater. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The input of human resources. This does not include management. Labour is chosen based on the skills, abilities, and education of the person. It is measured in work hours; the price is the wage rate. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An input of people who make the economic decisions on how, when, and what to produce. It is the task of allocating limited budget to maximize profits. |
|
|
Term
Total Physical Product (TPP) |
|
Definition
The quantity of an output produced in a period of time at a given input. The total physcial product curve or short run production function is a graph of TPP.
You can graph TPP of 2 inputs by making a 3 D graph. Cutting the graph horizontally wil give you the 2 D graph of the parallel input at a fixed amount of perpendicular input. |
|
|
Term
Average Physical Product (APP) |
|
Definition
A measure of outputs per inputs.
APP = TPP / Inputs
Draw a line on the TPP curve between the point and the origin. The slope of this line is APP. |
|
|
Term
Marginal Physcial Product (MPP) |
|
Definition
The change in output from a one unit change in input, as long as all other inputs stay the same.
MPP = ΔTPP / ΔInput
MPP is the derivative of TPP. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A set of input values in a production function where APP is increasing and MPP is greater than APP.
Each additional unit of input will increase productivity; output is increasing at an increasing rate. It is never good to be in Stage 1 because in this stage it is always better to increase inputs.
Stage 1 ends when APP = MPP. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A set of input values in a production function where APP is decreasing and MPP is below APP, but is still positive.
Output is increasing at a decreasing rate.
It is always good to be in Stage 2 because changing inputs may decrese efficiency.
Stage 2 ends when MPP = 0. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A set of input values in a production function where MPP is 0 or less.
Output is decreasing. It is always bad to be in Stage 3 because in this stage you can always do better by decreasing inputs. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Horizontal contour lines on a TPP graph with 2 inputs (3D graph) where output is at a constant number. They can be made 2D by looking at the graph from above. In 2D isoquants are always downward sloping. If one input is fixed, it leaves only one point on the isoquant where production will be.
Producing at levels northeast off of the isoquant indicates an inefficient producer.
Where it crosses the iso-cost line is a possible production point. When the iso-cost is tangent to it, that is optimal production.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When two inputs are perfectly interchangable. Whether you use one or the other or a combination does not effect output. When price decreases for one input, it reduces the demand on the other input.
The isoquants appear to be straight, downward sloping lines. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When two inputs must be applied in exact proportions. Having more of one than the other means you will have the output of that of the limiting input. When price decreases for one input, it reduces demand for the other input.
The isoquants are L shaped. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A concept that applies only to long-term systems. When you increase every input by a certain amount and measure what happens to output. May be decreasing, constant, or increasing. |
|
|
Term
Decreasing returns to scale |
|
Definition
When you increase all inputs and get an increased output level that is smaller than the amount you increased inputs. Returns to scale is a long-term concept but if you increased all variable inputs in a short-term system, you would always get decreasing returns to scale because of the one (or more) fixed inputs. |
|
|
Term
Constant returns to scale |
|
Definition
When you increase all inputs and get an increase in outputs proportionally equal to the increase in inputs. |
|
|
Term
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRTS) |
|
Definition
The amount of input that can be substituted for another input which maintaining a constant output. Or the rate at which a consumer can substitute two goods and be at the same utility.
MRTS = -ΔInput1 / ΔInput 2
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Two inputs that are not perfect substitutes of each other, but are not perfect complements either.
The isoquants are downward sloping curved lines. |
|
|
Term
Increasing Returns to Scale |
|
Definition
When you increase all your inputs and get an increase in outputs greater than the increase in inputs. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Allso called a budget. A line added to the isoquant diagram. It tells what combinations of the two outputs will add up to a constant cost. Its slope is the negative of the ratio of the input prices.
C = wL + rK
C = the budget
w = wage rate
L = amount of labour
r = price of capital
K = amount of capital
C, w, and r are fixed, so we get a 2 unknown equation (a line). If C increases, the isocost goes northeast. The slope of the line equals -w/r. If the price of an input changes, the slope changes.
Where it crosses the isoquant it is a possible production level. When it is tangent to the isoquant it is the most optimal point: cost is as low as possible for that isoquant. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
MPPL/w = MPPK/r
L = labour
w = wage rates
K = capital
r = price of capital
The marginal product per dollar on one input is always equal to the marginal product per dollar on a second input. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Demands for inputs effect production when trying to achieve cost-minimal inputs. If you have a demand curve for the output, you have the demand curve for the inputs needed for that output.
The demand for an input can be determined by the optimal point on an isoquant/iso-cost diagram.
Technical change can alter it. Input demand increases with increased input use, increased input productivity, or decrease in price of substitute inputs or competing outputs. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The fixed costs of a firm. The "overhead": a straight, horizontal line. Pay the same amount, regarless of output level. |
|
|
Term
Total Variable Cost (TVC) |
|
Definition
The total cost of variable inputs of a firm. Varies depending on output level. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Costst that are paid for from the pocket of the firm owner. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Costs that are not paid for with money, but give implicit value to the firm. Resources already owned and their opportunity costs. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A cost a firm has to pay regardless of output level, such as rent, tax, et cetera. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A cost a firm has to pay that varies depending on output level. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The total cost a firm pays. Fixed costs plus variable costs. Dependent on output levels. When graphed over outputs it increases at an increasing rate until it bends backwards. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The amount of fixed cost paid per unit of ouptut. Declines over the entire range of production since fixed outputs stay constant.
AFC = TFC / Output |
|
|
Term
Average Variable Cost (AVC) |
|
Definition
The amount of variable cost per unit of output. U-shaped on a graph. In agriculture it can be more like an L shape. Firms need to be very large before average costs rise.
AVC = TVC / Output |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The average total cost for every unit of output. It is average fixed and variable costs added together. Its minimum intersects with MC.
ATC = AFC + AVC.
or
ATC = (TFC + TVC) / Output |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The increase in costs necessary to increase total output by one more unit. It intersects ATC at its minimum value.
MC = ΔTC / Δq
q = quantity of output |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Includes Stages 1, 2, and 3 as you increase in outputs. In some cases stages may be missing or in a different order, or just one stage for the entire range of outputs. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Different from economy of size. It is about the increase in output when there is a change in input. A technical relationship, nothing to do with money. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Different from economy of scale, but called this by some textbooks. A percentage change in costs compared to the percentage change in outputs. |
|
|
Term
Long-Run Average Cost (LRAC) |
|
Definition
Using a number of different firm sizes and their average costs, the large curve that covers the lowest points of these combined. Once investments are made, it is difficult to change firm size, but in the long run any firm size is possible. It is U shaped. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Milk produced to be drunken or processed at a consumer level. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Milk produced to be processed into milk products. |
|
|
Term
Increasing Returns to Size |
|
Definition
When the long-run average costs decrease as outputs expands. On the downward slope of the LRAC.
1. Physical reasons: it doesn't take twice as much more labour to run a farm twice as big.
2. Indivisibility of outputs: large firms can use larger more efficient equipment.
3. Specialization of effort: larger firms it can have more specialized labour.
4. Pecuniary factors: discounts on large volume inputs. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the increase in costs is proportionally equal to the increase in output. The minimum on the LRAC. In agricultural systems this region can be very large. |
|
|
Term
Decreasing Returns to Size |
|
Definition
When the increase in costs is greater than the proportional increase in outputs. The upwards slope on the LRAC.
1. Operation encounters technical inefficiencies
2. Not enough management to handle the whole firm (this is why large corporations divide into smaller sections). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A tenet of economic analysis. We assume:
1. Goods produced by different firms are identicle
2. Firms can enter or exit the industry without cost
3. There is no risk or uncertainty
4. The price of the product is known
5. There are no costs to finding a buyer
6. The actions of other firms don't effect the firm
7. The actions of the firm doesn't effect the market; the firm is a price taker. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A firm that is so small that no matter how much it produces, it cannot change the price of the product; it must take the price that the prouct is at. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Revenue minus costs. It is the goal of all firms to maximize this. This maximum point occurs where MC is equal to MR. At this point, marginal profit is 0 (it is the peak of the curve). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The returns generated by the firm.
TR = (product price)*(output level) |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The revenue per unit of output. This is a constant equal to price for price-taking firms.
AR = TR/Output |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The change in revenue from producing more output. The slope of TR.
MR = ΔTR/ΔOutput |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The term used to describe when a firm is making 0 profits. Not losing money, but not making money either. At any point below this point there are losses, but a firm may still produce because they are trying to minimize losses. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The price at which a firm will exit the industry. In the short-run this is where ATC intersects with MC. In the long run it is where AC intersects with MC. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
As the market price for a good increases, so does supply. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The amount of product the industry suppies to a market. |
|
|
Term
Own-Price Elasticity of Supply (ε) |
|
Definition
The proportional change in supply in response to a change in price. Not to be confused with the slope of the supply curve. If you know the slop of the supply curve, price, and quantity, you can calculate ε.
ε = ΔQ / ΔP = (ΔQ*P) / (ΔP*Q) |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The person who invented the Marshallian scissors and supply curves.
Came up with the equation
Q = -a + Pb; ceterus paribus
Q is used as the dependent variable in this equation but on a graph it should be the independent variable.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A Latin saying which means "if everything else in the world remains constant." |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A horizontal supply curve. The price is fixed at a certain point, regarless of production.
ε = ∞ |
|
|
Term
Imperfecty elastic supply |
|
Definition
A shallow supply curve. A small change in price results in a big change in quantity.
1 < ε < ∞ |
|
|
Term
Imperfectly inelastic supply |
|
Definition
A steep supply curve. A big change in price results in a small change in quantity. This is frequently seen in agriculture.
0 < ε < 1 |
|
|
Term
Perfectly inelastic supply |
|
Definition
A verticle supply curve. No change in price can change the quantity.
ε = 0. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Price graphed over quantity produced by the industry. It can shift up/left if input prices go up, or if a competing output's price goes up. It can shift down/right if there is technological improvement, if the price is anticipated to rise, or if more producers join the industry. It can sometimes pivot, maintaining a constant shut-down point. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
In the long-run, the price range bellow MC and above AC. If MC is bellow AC, there are economic losses. As long as this number is positive, firms will enter the industry. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
In the long-run the price range above MC and below AC. If MC is above AC, there are economic profits. As long as this number is positive, firms will exit the industry. |
|
|
Term
Value of Total Product (VTP) |
|
Definition
|
|
Term
Value of Marginal Product (VMP) |
|
Definition
|
|
Term
Value of Average Product (VAP) |
|
Definition
|
|
Term
|
Definition
To add intermediate or fixed assets to a business. They need to be analysed because money is spent, and the effects are usually long-term. There are four kinds.
1. Replacing worn out or obsolete capital
2. Adopting new technology
3. Expansion
4 Adding new enterprises |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The uncertainty in life. It may be quantified using probability or subjective analysis. Investments you make may not pay you back for some reason outside of your control. Extra money may paid to insurance companies to cover these costs in case this happens. There are risk premiums you can get for taking risk. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A factor in investment analysis. When the dollars you get back from an investment do not have the same buying power as the dollars invested initially. To componsate for this, adjust the discount rate. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
In investments, people tend to prefer to consume now rather than later, perhaps lessening the time of the investment. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The number of dollars available at the current time. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The amount of money available from an investment at some time in the future. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The number of dollars to be paid or recieved at the end of each of a number of periods. |
|
|
Term
Interest/Discount Rate (i) |
|
Definition
Often the opportunity cost of capital. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The number of a time period that has passed. Years, months, or days. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A series of equal and periodic payments.
FV = PMT((1+i)n-1/i)
PV = PMT(1-(1+i)-n/i) |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
To calculate future value when the present value is known. Depends on the present value, interest rate, and length of timet that passes. The oppostie of discounting.
FV = PV(1+i)n |
|
|
Term
Locked-In Retirement Account (LIRA) |
|
Definition
An investment account where the money is unavailable to you until you retire. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A person who mnages someone else's money. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Calculating present values when the future value is known. E.g., How much should I invest if I want X amount of money in X amount of years? The opposite of compounding.
PV = (FV)/((1+i)n) |
|
|
Term
Investment Analysis/Capital Budgeting |
|
Definition
The process of determining the profitability of an investment. Used when deciding what investments to make. Find out:
1. What are the returns?
2. Is it feasible in terms of cash flow?
Need to know:
1. Periodic net cash revenues
2. Initial cost
3. Terminal value
4. Interest rate
There are four kinds of investment analysis:
1. Payback period
2. Simple rate of return
3. Net present value
4. Iternal rate of return. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A form of investment analysis which looks at how long an investment would take to pay for itself. It is easy to use, shows what inestments have most immediate cash returns, but ignores cash flow after payback period, doesn't account for time value of money, and does not measure profitability.
P = I/E
P = payback period
I = initial cost
E = expected average annual net revenue. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A form of investment analysis which tells us the average net revenue as a percentage of the initial cost. It looks at an investment's earnings over the whole period, but fails to consider the size and timing of anual earnings, and doesn't consider the time value of money.
ROR = ((anual net cash revenue)-(average depreciation))/(investment) |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The best form of investment analysis. If this value is greater than 0, this is a valid investment. It accounts for the time value of money, does not have misleading results, and considers inflation.
NPV = (P1/(1+i)1) + (P2/(1+i)2) + ... -c
P = cash fow in year n
i = discount rate
c = initial cost |
|
|
Term
Internal Rate of Return (IRR) |
|
Definition
The discount rate (i) that makes NPV equal to 0. To find, set NPV equal to 0 and solve for i. Can use trial and error, or a software program. If the IRR is greater than the opportunity cost, the investment is profitable. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A factor in investment analysis. It reduces the net cash revenues depending on the marginal tax practiced. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A number between 0 and 1, expressed as a percentage, which indicates the likelihood that an outcome will occur.
P = (number of times the outcome occured last year)/(total number of possible times it could have happened) |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A way of quantifing risk based on personal experience or professional knowledge. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The weighted average value of an investment based on two or more possible outcomes in a risky situation.
EV = P1V1 + P2V2 ...
P = probability of different outcomes
V = value of different outcomes |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A measure of risk. The distance between the minimum and maximum possible value. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A measure of risk that uses Expected Value (EV).
Variance = P1(V1- EV)2 + P2(V2 -EV)2 ...
P = probability of different outcomes
V = value of different outcomes. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A weighted average of the utility from two or more possible outcomes.
EU = P1U1 + P2U2 ...
P = probability of different outcomes.
U = utility of different outcomes. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A situation where the expected value is exactly zero. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A term to describe a person who would not take a fair bet. Utility rises with wealth at a decreasing rate. This category of person would pay a risk premium to avoid taking risk. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Money paid to avoid taking risks. A risk averse person would pay this. The consequences of the risk, should they happen, will be covered by the risk premium. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A term to describe a person who neither avoids nor seeks out risk. Utility increases with wealth in a straight line. This person would chose options with the highest expected value. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A term to describe a person who will take a fair bet. They would pay to make a fair bet, the oposite of a risk premium. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A situation where the expected value is negative. E.g. casinos or lottery tickets. People who may otherwise be risk averse may take bets like this due to gambling addiction, gambling for entertainment, or making mistakes. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
1. Don't do risky activities (gambling, lottery, leaving your house unlocked)
2. Obtain information on your decisions.
3. Diversify your investments, especially with negatively correlated things.
4. Get insurance.
|
|
|
Term
Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution |
|
Definition
The ratio of the MPP of two inputs. The slope of the isoquant. When this is equal to the slope of the iso-cost line, cost is minimized. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Every consumer has their own utility function. Everyone has differet tastes and preferences. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The level of satisfaction derived from consuming goods and services. It is measured by asking a person to arbitrarily assign a number to how they feel and then compare those numbers to various consumption packages. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A particular combination of goods and/or services. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The algabraic exressino that allows us to rank a consumption bundle by the total utility or satisfaction it provides. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
As demographics of a population changes, so does demand for various goods. Cuisine changes with more immigration from other countries. The Baby Boom generation is getting old. Older people want to eat healthier foods. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Recalling bad food is important for food safety. Dramatic drops in demand in a whole genre of foods can be seen from just one recal in one product. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
People want to buy ethical foods such as fair trade coffee. They are willing to pay extra for it. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
People want to buy foods that are good for the environment, such as organic foods and local foods. |
|
|
Term
De gustibus non est disputandum |
|
Definition
"There is no accounting for tastes" |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The change in utility from one additional unit of a good or service. This value decreases and then goes negative.
MU = ΔUtility / ΔQuantity |
|
|
Term
Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility |
|
Definition
As the amount consumed of a good increases, its marginal utility eventually decreases, possibly becoming negative. |
|
|
Term
Canadian Cattle Association |
|
Definition
An association which takes money from each sale of beef and puts it into beef marketing (Canadian as well as international) and beef research. Generic marketing campaigns for a general product. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A graph of combinations of two goods that provides an equal level of utility. Downward sloping. Its slope is the marginal rate of substitution. Where it touches the budget constraint, that is the consumption bundle the consumer will choose to purchase. |
|
|
Term
Own-Price Elasticity of Demand (η) |
|
Definition
Shows how demand for a good will change in response to a change in the good's price. Not the same as a slope coefficient.
η = Δ%Q / Δ%P |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The amount of money a consumer has available to spend on goods and services. Expenditures are found by multiplying quantity by price of each good and adding them together.
It can be graphed as a straight line where combinations of two goods add up to the same budget. Where this line crosses the indifference curve, the consmer will consume that consumption bundle. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A graph showing the amount of a good that a consumer will purchase at different prices. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A table showing the optimal price-quantity combinations for a consumer. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A good that you consume more of when your income rises. The Engel curve is upward sloping.
Income elasticity of demand is between 0 and 1.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A good that you consume less of when your income rises. The Engel curve is downward sloping.
Income elasticity of demand is less than zero.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A curve showing the relationship between income and quantity of a good consumed at fixed prices. Invented by Frederick Engel. It's slope determines whether a good is inferior or normal. It gives the income elasticity of demand. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The man who invented the Engel curve. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The portion of income spent on food. In wealthier countries it is smaller. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The sum of all the individual demands. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The quantity demanded of a good and its price are inversely related. Demand curves are downward sloping. |
|
|
Term
Change in Quantity Demanded |
|
Definition
The movement along a demand curve when the price of a good changes, all other things are held constant. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A shift in the demand curve resulting from chnges other than own-price changes. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Goods that can substitute each other. When the price of one goes up, the demand for the other goes up.
Cross-price elasticity is positive. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Goods that are used together. When the price of one goes up, the demand for the other goes down.
Cross-price elasticity is negative. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Goods that have no connection to each other. If the price of one goes up, the demand of the other in unaffected.
Cross-price elasticity is zero. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When own-price elasticity is greater than 1.
η > 1 |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the own-price elasticity is equal to 1.
η = 1 |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the own-price elasticity is less than 1.
η < 1 |
|
|
Term
Income Elasticity of Demand |
|
Definition
Given by the Engel Curve.
Income elasticity of demand = %ΔQuantity demanded / %Δ Income |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A normal good where the income elasticity is greater than 1. |
|
|
Term
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand |
|
Definition
How much demand will change in response to a change in another good. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Not necessarily a physical space (example: eBay). Supply and demand are at work. A price is determined. The ownership of goods is transfered or services are provided. Composed of institutions. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Defined by:
1. Homogenous products (standards).
2. Freedom of entry and exit (no entry/exit costs).
3. Many buyers and sellers (no one firms actions can effect the entire market).
4. Perfect information (all buyers and sellers are fully informed on prices, quantities, and quality). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When all the traders in a market are able to buy ad sell as much as they want. The market clears (supply equals demand). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The price of a good or service at market equilibrium. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The quantity supplied of a good or service at market equilibrium. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The amount of good that consumers are willing to buy at a given price (all other factors held constant). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A graph of quantity demanded plotted on quantity (x-axis) and price (y-axis). |
|
|
Term
Double coincidence of wants |
|
Definition
When two parties agree on a trade (usually of goods or services for money). Unless this can happen, no fair trade can occur.
Non-market goods are hard to trade. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The mathematical equation for the demand curve. Factors can be added to it such as the price of other goods, and income. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The amount of goods that firms want to sell at a given price (other factors remain constant). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A graph of quantity supplied over quantity (x-axis) and price (y-axis). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The mathematical equation of the supply curve. Factors can be added such as other goods and income. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A mysterious force that causes markets to reach equilibrium. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the quantity demand is bigger than the quantity supply at a given price. This is the area below the market equilibrium on a supply-demand diagram. This drives the price upwards toward equilibrium. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the quantity supplied exceeds the quantity demanded. This is the area above the market equilibrium on a supply and demand diagram. This drives the price downward toward market equilbrium. |
|
|
Term
Shock to the market equilibrium |
|
Definition
When there is a shift in th supply curve or demand curve. Caused by a change in price of other goods, or income. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Caused by change in price of other products or in income. Increase in demand raises price and quantity. Decrease in demand lowers price and quantity. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Caused by a change in price of other products or in income. Decrease in supply causes prices to raise and demand to decrease. Increase in supply causes prices to lower and demand to decrease. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Costs associated with finding a buyer/seller, and transfering ownership of goods or services (additional to price of good/service). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The analysis of the impact of a change on the welbeing of various groups.
Not to be confused with government payments to the poor. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
This causes the government to intervene. Can occur when:
1. Markets not present (air, water, food safety)
2. Monopoly control (one firm with disproportionate power over the market)
3. People do not have full information (grades, standards, publications). |
|
|
Term
Things the government supplies |
|
Definition
Law and order, national defense, highways, communication, healthcare, contract law, weights, measures, grades, standards, supply management, |
|
|
Term
Reasons for government intervention |
|
Definition
1. Support and protect a new industry
2. Curb the market power of potential monopolizers
3. Provide food security
4. Consumer health and safety (sanitary requirements, grades and standards, labelling requirements, health and nutrition recommendations, taxing bad things (tobacco, alcohol, junk food)).
5. Environmental protection
6. Accesible food (prices, food programs).
7. Development of rural communities
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The benefit consumers ged from consuming a good, minus what the consumer paid for the good. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Sales tax. Takes away a proportion of the expentitures on a purchase (based on price, not quantity). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Tax based on quantity rather than price. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A form of government intervention. Causes a deadweight loss. Effects depend on the elasticity of demand of a good. |
|
|
Term
Marginal willingness to pay |
|
Definition
The maximum amount a consumer will spend for an additional unit of a good. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The monetary difference between what the consumer was willing to pay, minus what the consumer paid. The area of the triangle sided by the Price axis, Demand curve, and Price line on the bottom. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The economic return bove a firm's variable cost of production. Area of triangle with sides of Price axis, Supply curve, and Price line. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Consumer surplus plus producer surplus. The area of the triangle with sides of the Price axis, Demand curve, and Supply Curve.
A competitive market will reach the highest value for this. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The total economic surplus that is lost as a result of government intervention. Often it is quite small in comparison to government revenue or increase in consumer/producer surplus. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A minimum price, set by an institution. Only effective if the minimum price is greater than the equilibrium price. Consumer surplus decreases and supplyer surplus increases. There is some deadweight loss. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A maximum price, set by an institution. Only effective if it is lower than the equilibrium price. Consumer surplus increases, and supplyer surplus decreases. There is some deadweight loss. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
In Canada dairy, eggs, and poultry have supply management. It puts a limit on supply. Price is higher than in an equilibrium. Consumer surplus is less, but producer surplus is greater. There is some deadweight loss. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
To send goods or services out to another country. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
To bring in goods or services from another country. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
-Cannot produce this good in a country, must import it.
-Regional price differences present a proffit opportunity. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The cost to transport a good to another region. If trade is a free market, this cost will be equal to the difference in equilibrium price of the two regions. If the price difference is less than transfer cost, no trade will occur. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Buying in a low-price market and then selling in a high-price market. If the transfer cost is more than the difference in price, arbitrage will not happen. At equilibrium transfer cost is equal to difference in price. The difference in price is not higher than transfer cost for very long.
Arbitrage raises price in the low-priced market, and lowers price in the high-priced market. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The prices in a closed market where no trade is allowed between two regions. If the market is "opened", prices will fall in the high price region, and rise in the low-price region. |
|
|
Term
Number of Firms and Size Distribution |
|
Definition
A characteristic of a market. Competitive conditions break down as the number of firm decreases and size of firms increases. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A characteristic of a market. The degree to which products are differentiated. May be no actual differences in products or production, only percieved differences based on brand. The higher the differentiation, the the more suppiers can raise price. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
If barriers are low, firms in highly concentrated industries have little opportunity to set high prices.
-Absolute unit: when there is no level of output where the firm can operate competitively.
-Economies of scale: small firms face high costs, new firms need to be large to enter.
-Capital access and costs: industries with large initial investment costs
-Preferential government policies: patents, copyrigts, import controls. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Three aspects of supply/demand
1. Level of output in industry: larger volume = more profit opportunity for firms.
2. Responsiveness of supply/demand to price changes: more elastic demand = more opportunities for firms.
3. Proportion of food expenditures accounted for by the industry's product: smaller portion = growth will stagnate. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
1. Price competition
2 Monopolistic competition
3. Oligopoly
4. Monopoly |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
1. Pure competition
2. Monopsonistic competition
3. Oligopsony
4. Monopsony |
|
|
Term
Perfect competition (sellers) |
|
Definition
Very many sellers. Product is not differentiation. Entry and exit is unrestricted. No ability to set price. No excess profit. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Many sellers. Product is differentiated. Entry/exit is unrestricted. Some ability to set price. No excess profit. The more sellers, the less deadweight loss.
Competition focuses on conditions of sale, advertisement, differentiation of products, brand reputation, location in store. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Few sellers. Product may be differentiated. Some ability to set price. There is excess profit. A firm's decisions are effected by the actions or anticipated actions of the competition. May enter price-cutting wars. Price is stable.
Exist because of product differentiation, high entry costs, dependence on long-term research/development, problems with access to markets, or aggressive corporate growth strategies.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
One seller. Product is unique. Exit/entry is completely restricted. There is excess profit. Produces where marginal cost = marginal revenue. There is deadweight loss.
They exist because they may control a key input, have superior technology, more efficient by some nature of the industry, government action (hospitals), patents. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An illegal activity where all the firms in an oligopoly decide upon a price that is just slightly higher than the free market price, and they profit off of it. Hard to detect because it is only a tiny increase in price, but can cause billions in profit. If caught, the punishments are severe. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When a firm charges different prices for the same product (due to some percived difference, like brand), or charges less per unit for a greater amount of the product. Creates profits for the firm. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Charging different prices to different customers to maximize profits. Firm must have market power, consumers must be non-uniform in demand elasticity, the firm must be able to evaluate different demand elasticities, and the firm must be able to prevent resales. There is:
1. perfect price discrimination
2. quantity discrimination
3. mult-market price discrimination |
|
|
Term
Perfect Price Discrimination |
|
Definition
Each product is sold at the highest price the customer is willing to pay. Done by haggling or auctioning. Real estate, boats, cars. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The firm charges a different price for large vs. small quantities. Not price discrimination if the firm passes on actual cost savings. Example: hydro bill different based on usage bracket. |
|
|
Term
Multi-market Price Discrimination |
|
Definition
The firm charges different groups of customers different prices. Based on observable physical characteristics, or the method the customer seeks to purchase the product (phone/in-store). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The customer pays first for the right to use the product, then pays for the actual product. Example: health club membership, telephone services, car rentals. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A customer may only buy a good/service if they also buy another good/service. Example: vacation packages with air fare + hotel accomodation. There may be per-unit price differences in these sales. There is requirement tie-in, and bundling. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When customers cannot purchase the good/service without purchasing the second related good/service from the same firm. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When two or more goods are combined in a package so that customers cannot buy them separately. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A process that begins with the acquisition of raw materials, and ends with the distribution and sale of finished goods/services. |
|
|
Term
Vertical Boundaries of a Firm |
|
Definition
The activities a single firm undergoes in the vertical chain. Some firms may actually undergo every step of the process, where others purchase and sell in one portion somewhere along the chain. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The decision a firm makes when defining its vertical boundaries. Do we make this ourselves or do we hire another firm to make it?
Specialized firms will be more efficient, but buyers want to avoid being swindled by the other firm.
Good to buy because it can cause lower average costs. A vertically integrated firm will have a smaller size than a market firm, and will have difficulty adjusting to demand shifts.
Good to make, because you avoid transaction costs. Co-ordination of production is better. Keep private information safe.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When a firm's actions directly effect the welfare of other people, consumers or otherwise. Can be negative or positive. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An externality that lowers other's welfare. Example: bad smells, loud noise. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An externality that increases other's welfare. Example: outdoor shrubs, good smells (bakery). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Costs that the firm itself pays. The cost of production, not including externalities. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Costs that the firm doesn' pay. Externality costs are paid for by others. Example: pollution clean-up. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Private costs plus external costs.
Firms produce where private costs equal revenue, rather where social costs equal revenue. This creates a deadweight loss. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A resource or facility that is open to public access by anyone. This may lead to the Tradegy of the Commons. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When common property is overused because every individual is trying to maximize what they take from it.
Canbe solved by government regulation (taxes, entrance fee, restricted access), or property rights (convert into a commodity, auction it off). |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A good with no rivalry. Example: scenery. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A good with rivalry. Example: food. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When only one person/group can consume the good. It cannot be reused or resold. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When you can prevent others from consuming a good, such as when you have property rights to something. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When someone benefits from another's actions without paying. It can be reduced by social pressure, merging into a group, compulsion from an outside force, or privatization. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When one party in a transaction knows a fact the other party does not. The informed party benefits at the expense of the non-informed party. Causes adverse selection and moral hazard.
|
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A problem caused by asymmetric informaion when the informed party benefits because they know an unobserved characteristic that the uninformed party is unaware of. Example: buying life insurance and having an unhealthy lifestyle without the insurance company's knowledge.
Ways to prevent it:
Laws, screening, third party comparisons, standards, certifications, signaling by firm. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A problem caused by asymmetric information where the informed party undertakes an action the uninformed party is unaware of. Example: an employee not working hard, stealing, or taking very long breaks when the employer isn't watching.
Ways to avoid: contracts (fixed-fee, hire, and contingent), monitoring, bonding, deferred payments, efficiency wages. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A solution to adverse selection where the uninformed party searches for concealed characteristics. Example: test-driving a car. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A solution to adverse selection where the informed person informs the uninformed person. Exmple: employees using resumes and references to ensure the employer of their abilities. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Payment is made to the agent independent of their actions. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The principle pays the agent depending on their actions: hourly or piece rate. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
The principle and agent are payed based on state of nature. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A contract that ensures that neither party is made better or worse off. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Paying an employee based on output. Encourages them to work harder. Practical only if output is easily measurable. Can lead to elicit behaviour. Can be bad to persuade workers to accept piece rate work. Can encourage not-so-good work. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
Paying an employee based on the hours they work. Works if output is difficult to measure. Can encourage shirking. Can encourage taking one's time and doing a good job. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
A contract that discourages employees to take a job at a competing firm. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the principle requires the agent to deposit funds prior to taking the job, ensuring their performance. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
When the firm pays new workers low wages for an initial period and then increases wages later, firing those who shirk. |
|
|
Term
|
Definition
An unusually high wage that makes the employee fearfull of being fired, thus discouraging shirking of any kind. |
|
|